BEFORE THE WASHINGTON UTILITIES AND TRANSPORTATION COMMISSION In the Matter of the Petition for Investigation into the Cost of Universal Service and to Reform Intrastate Access Charges, and Obligation to Serve Requirement. Docket No. UT-970325 COMMENTS OF DR. MARK N. COOPER ON BEHALF OF THE ATTORNEY GENERAL OF WASHINGTON PUBLIC COUNSEL SECTION APRIL 17, 1998 FIRST SET OF STAFF QUESTIONS (Notice of March 23, 1998) 1. How should the obligation to serve differ, if at all, between: a. The obligation of an incumbent to serve its retail customers and to provide unbundled network elements (UNEs) and resale services to its wholesale customers? The history and nature of these two obligations differs considerably. The obligation to serve has its origins in the public policy of universal service and in common carrier principles. Charles F. Phillips, Jr., The Regulation of Public Utilities, 3rd Edition, 1993, pp. 118-119. Many of the issues raised in this rulemaking were thoughtfully addressed by this Commission in its ruling on U S WEST Communications, Inc.=s, (USWC) AObligation to Serve@ tariff filing. WUTC v. USWC, UT 961638, Fourth Supplemental Order Rejecting Tariff Filing, January 16, 1998 (hereafter AUSWC Obligation to Serve Order@). The obligation to serve is deeply embedded in the common carrier tradition and public interest standards that have applied to utility services since the beginnings of the industry. It is required to furnish service to all that seek it within its territory. The economic, technical or other factors that the provider of service can invoke to refuse to provide service are very narrowly defined. The obligation to provide unbundled network elements and resale, by contrast has more recent origins in the public policy of promoting competition. The obligation of a monopoly, incumbent local exchange telephone company to provide unbundled network elements and resale derives from the Telecommunications Act of 1996. While these specific federal requirements are more recent, there has long existed an obligation to provide access to bottleneck elements. In addition, it should be noted that the interconnection obligations under Washington law are of long standing. Washington State Constitution, Article XII, Section 19. See also, RCW 80.36.200, 80.36.220. It is certainly possible that, as a competitive market develops and multiple service providers become capable of ensuring the availability of service to all in an area the obligation to serve that now falls on the incumbent can be shared or modified. The important point is that the obligation to serve is a public policy principle that comes first. It is paramount. Market structures may alter the way that public policy is achieved, but only if there is certainty that the goal will remain accomplished can such a change be made. 1. How should the obligation to serve differ, if at all, between: b. The obligations of an entrant to its retail customers and the obligation of an incumbent to its retail customers? The incumbent has had and continues to have the obligation to serve all. It is the carrier of last resort (COLR). The incumbent has ubiquitous facilities. It has deployed those facilities with significant benefits from ratepayers, including a monopoly position and regulatory rights to an opportunity to recover costs. The pervasive market presence and longstanding name recognition conferred on the incumbent also endow it with substantial assets as competition increases in the industry. The obligation to serve is a burden placed on the incumbents and compensated by historical and ongoing benefits of immense value. Incumbents are directly compensated by setting rates that are, in the aggregate, just and reasonable. They are provided an opportunity to recovery prudently incurred, used and useful costs. Should costs increase due to an increase in the burden of its carrier of last resort obligation, they can make a showing that they are in need of a rate increase. New entrants have no such opportunity. Incumbents are also compensated for specific expenses in cases where such costs would be extraordinary. See, USWC Obligation to Serve Order, p. 21. Indirectly, the benefits of the monopoly, incumbent ubiquitous network compensate the incumbent. Given the current market structure, with virtually no change in market share, no real choice for most customers, and no observable price competition, the obligation to serve falls fairly on the incumbent. See, USWC Obligation to Serve Order, pp. 22-23. New entrants do not enjoy any of the vast array of benefits that have been bestowed by the ratepayers on the incumbent. They lack market power and ubiquitous facilities. The typically have little if any track record in providing local service. They have not been the recipients of any of the historic benefits bestowed on the incumbents. As noted in response to Question 1a, the possibility of changes in the obligation to serve must be recognized. These will come about only over time as market structure actually changes. The Telecommunications Act of 1996 recognizes this. Under the Act, a new entrant who seeks to become eligible for universal service support funds incurs obligations that begin the transition from new entrant to candidate for carrier of last resort responsibilities. In essence, the new entrant would have to make services available to all customers in the area it services. It could, however, meet these obligations through a combination of its own facilities and facilities or services it purchases from the incumbent. ETC status is not equivalent to COLR status, in part because it is the underlying facilities that are central to meeting the obligation to serve. New entrant ETCs will likely have few facilities initially. Furthermore, while the federal Act establishes the ETC category as a funding mechanism, the states are entrusted with the ultimate authority to manage the transition from the current obligation to serve that uniquely falls on the incumbent to an obligation shared between the incumbent and new entrants. 1. How should the obligation to serve differ, if at all, between: c. The obligations of incumbents and new entrants with respect to customers outside any incumbent=s current exchange boundaries. Service to unserved areas should be provided in the most economical manner possible. In general this will mean that only service providers with proximity to the unserved area which have an existing carrier of last resort obligation should be considered as candidates to provide service to the unserved area. The provider that can serve an area at least cost should be selected. Further, as multiple carriers of last resort become available, it may be necessary to establish universal service funding to defray the extraordinary costs associated with extending service in unserved areas. Once again, the key to ascertaining when this fund is necessary is the observation and documentation of actual changes in market structure. At present, the incumbent has the obligation to serve and is compensated directly and indirectly for shouldering that obligation. At some point in the future, when competition has balanced revenue opportunities and new entrants have facilities deployed that could shoulder the obligation to serve, alternative approaches may be necessary. Contributions to a universal service fund to support the obligation to extend service or sharing of the obligation to extend facilities may be necessary. 1. How should the obligation to serve differ, if at all, between: d. The obligations of incumbents and new entrants to customers who switch to a competitor and then wish to return to their preceding service provider? The switch does not alter the obligation to serve. First, the switch may not entail a change in the use of underlying facilities, since the competitor may be serving the customer through resale or use of unbundled network element. Second, the existing tariffs are available to all customers. It does not matter whether the customer is returning from a year of graduate work in New York, a year working in Alaska, or a year of taking service from AT&T; all customers have a right to receive all tariffed services. Change may come to this process, however, as market structure evolves. If the incumbent has sought to be decertified as a carrier of last resort after the customer has left the state or switched to a competitor, then that customer would have the right to obtain service from the company which has newly been designated as the carrier of last resort. 1. How should the obligation to serve differ, if at all, between: e. The obligation of an incumbent to serve the additional demands of existing customers, for example, second lines, and its obligation to serve new customers within existing exchange boundaries? The obligation to serve does not distinguish between primary and second lines. A line is a line, subject to the rules of the tariffing process. 2. What conditions must exist before the Commission can permit an ILEC to be relieved of its obligation to provide service on demand within its serving area? Should the conditions include: a. Generally available (tariffed) terms and conditions for unbundled network elements and resale of services? The availability of unbundled network elements and resale, in and of itself, does not affect the obligation to serve. As noted, the obligation to serve has its origins in universal service policy while the offering of unbundled network elements and resale has its origins in competition policy. Moreover, the existence of unbundled network elements only underscores the need to have the provider who owns the underlying facilities be the carrier of last resort. Since the obligation to provide network elements and resale relates Aonly@ to competition, reliance on this commitment to meet the obligation to serve would reduce the level of assurance that the public will be served. 2. What conditions must exist before the Commission can permit an ILEC to be relieved of its obligation to provide service on demand within its serving area? Should the conditions include: b. The presence of effective competition in the service area at issue? If so, measured by what standard? A finding that an area is subject to effective competition could be a trigger for commencing the process of transforming the obligation to serve. The Commission would have to find more than just the presence of competition, however. The obligation to serve entails a commitment to meeting all demand. Competition would have to be based on ubiquitously available facilities that could serve all likely demand. Competition based on resale or unbundled network elements alone would not be adequate to ensure continued fulfillment of the obligation to serve. At the same time, a finding that an area is effectively competitive, based-upon a mix of unbundled network elements and facilities-based competition, could well mark a stage in which funds are raised from all the providers in the area in a competitively neutral manner to support the obligation to serve. It is likely that other changes would be made as well, which would reinforce the idea that the obligation to serve was changing. For example, in many states, because the finding that a service is subject to effective competition triggers different regulatory treatment under alternative regulation plans, it might become necessary to develop new ways to ensure that service obligations are met. 2. What conditions must exist before the Commission can permit an ILEC to be relieved of its obligation to provide service on demand within its serving area? Should the conditions include: c. The existence of more than one eligible telecommunications carrier (ETC) in the service area at issue? As discussed elsewhere in these comments, there is a distinction between and ETC and a COLR. The existence of ETCs for an area does not automatically relieve the ILEC of its obligations. 3. What difference, if any, is there between the obligation to serve requirement imposed by RCW 80.36.090, and the requirement that an ETC offer basic service in its designated service area? Are obligation to serve and universal service concepts necessarily related to each other? The obligation to serve and ETC are different concepts. As noted above, the obligation to serve is a broad concept relating to the relationship between customers and the utility supplier. ETC is a concept defined primarily by a cost question - is the area high cost and is the company eligible to receive universal service support to defray costs that the public cannot afford to support through rates? The Telecommunications Act of 1996, as implemented by the FCC, has imposed conditions on the right to receive this support, which capture some aspects, but not all aspects of the obligation to serve. See, In the Matter of Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, CC Docket 96-45, FCC 97-157, Report and Order, May 8, 1997, && 134-180. As stated in response to question 2.b., this may provide a beginning for the transition in the obligation to serve. However, the authority to effectuate that transformation resides solely at the state level. If the Telecommunications Act has any impact on the transformation, it will be through its competition policy that will help to bring about the market structure transformation that must precede any change in the obligation to serve. 4. For purposes of fulfilling the obligation to serve requirement, are ILECs= designated (tariffed) service areas appropriate, or could some other geographic area be considered? Given the current market structure, the ILECS= service areas are the appropriate areas. As described earlier, as market structure changes it may be possible to define different areas. This will occur as purely facilities-based competitive carriers are able to ensure service in their designated areas. In such an area, the incumbent might be decertified after the competitor has been certified as the COLR. 5. Section 214 (e)(3) requires state commissions to designate an ETC for unserved areas of the state. What process should the Commission use to designate provider(s) that will have an obligation to serve currently unserved areas of the state? If a case-by-case approach is recommended, what specific criteria should the Commission consider? The process should be case-by-case. The criteria should include the following: (1) The carrier to be designated must be a facilities-based carrier with responsibility for the provision of all facilities necessary to provide service. (2) The selected carrier should be chosen on the basis of the lowest cost to provide the service. For the immediate future, contiguous ILECs will be the most likely candidates. 6. What service(s) should be provided pursuant to the statutory obligation to provide service requirement? Should the service(s) provided differ depending upon whether the customer is located in an existing exchange area or in an unserved area? Pursuant to state law and regulation the obligation to serve applies to all tariffed services. At a minimum, the services provided should include those designated for universal service support. This would include the federally defined services plus any services that the state adds to the list. There should be no difference between served and unserved areas. 7. Do the FCC infrastructure sharing rules, implementing Sec. 259 necessitate consideration by the Commission of state specific infrastructure sharing rules? The section 259 obligations are not as strong as the obligation to serve obligation. Therefore, they could not replace the obligations to serve. Infrastructure sharing is one of the elements that may contribute to the change in the obligation to serve in the long term. In any event, infrastructure sharing is directly relevant only to unserved areas. 8. Are the availability of tariffed terms and conditions for unbundled network elements, resale, and infrastructure sharing sufficient to ensure that non-ILEC carriers could provide service under an obligation to serve requirement in designated service areas? No. As noted, the UNEs and resale deal only with competition, not universal service and the obligation to serve. These terms cannot ensure that the obligation to serve is met. Infrastructure sharing is a discretionary program that lacks the ability to ensure the provision of facilities necessary to accomplish the obligation to serve. 9. Are there any legal, institutional, or market factors that the Commission should consider in altering the existing ILECs= obligation to serve? As noted, the local exchange market may be commencing a process that will require changes in the obligation to serve in the decades ahead. That the process may take decades is a reflection of the fact that the ubiquitous telecommunications network that exists today was built up over the course of almost a century. Claims that legal or market forces require precipitous changes in the obligation to serve are simply wrong. There has been virtually no change in the structure of the local exchange market. Incumbents still have virtual monopolies. Moreover, the facilities that are most likely to be left stranded by changes in market structure are also the least likely to be subject to marketplace change. Only dedicated loop facilities are generally incapable of being utilized when a customer is Alost@ to a competitor. Most other facilities are shared between customers and can be used to meet other demands. Those loop facilities are the most difficult to supplant and are likely to remain utilized as unbundled network elements. See, USWC Obligation to Serve Order, p. 21. Thus, the Commission should monitor actual marketplace developments to ascertain whether facilities are being deployed by competitors which could provide the backbone on which an obligation to serve could be built. Neither the telecommunications Act, nor Washington law requires a precipitous change in the obligation to serve. The Telecommunications Act clearly recognizes that incumbents are in a superior position to new entrants in a variety of ways. It imposes heavier burdens on them in light of these advantages. The Act also reserves to the states the authority to administer the obligation to serve. Common law and state law recognizes the difference between the incumbent with its monopoly position and new entrants. See generally, USWC Obligation to Serve Order, pp. 24-26. 10. Can the limits of an obligation to serve requirement be defined by technology?; by business plan?; by any other attribute other than a tariff? No. Once a service is tariffed, it must be made available to the public subject to the obligation to serve. It is generally true, however, that so long as a company does not deploy a technology or offer a service subject to tariff (as part of its business plan) it cannot be compelled to deliver a service that does not exist to a requesting customer. At the same time, the Commission can find that a refusal to deploy a specific technology or offer a specific service is not in the public interest. It would order the company to tariff and offer the service. At that point, it would become subject to the obligation to serve any customer who requested the service. 11. What other issues, not addressed here, should be addressed by a Commission rule concerning the obligation to serve requirement? None at this time. 12. Do wireless providers have an obligation to provide service within their designated serving areas? Can the commission designate wireless providers as ETCs? Wireless provides do not have an obligation to serve comparable to that of ILECs under present conditions. Commission jurisdiction over wireless carriers is limited. Wireless telecommunications service at present price levels is not a realistic alternative to POTS. If these issues are resolved, to the extent that wireless carriers begin to operate like CLECs, their obligations could be found to be comparable to CLEC obligations. Wireless carriers can be designated as ETCs if they meet the federal criteria for ETC status. AUCTION QUESTIONS (Notice of April 1, 1998) 1. Proposals have suggested the use of auctions (bidding process) to determine which provider(s) would serve high-cost locations: a. Could a bid process work to ensure service in presently unserved areas? The idea that an auction could help to make the obligation to serve process more Aefficient@ may sound attractive, but given the current market structure it would do no good and might do harm. The incumbent has ubiquitously deployed facilities and enjoys substantial economies of scale and scope. New entrants do not. They will not be able to bid against the incumbent effectively under current circumstances. Auction processes that fail to recognize the immense advantage that incumbents possess can have the perverse effect of raising the cost of meeting the obligation to serve. The incumbent can easily game the auction process by bidding higher than its cost of services (which reflects economies of scale and scope) and lower than the cost competitors who lack economies can bid. If the incumbent is allowed to claim that the public should pay the price set by the winning bid, the incumbent can earn excessive returns by capturing for itself the benefits of economies of scale and scope, rather than sharing them with the public. b. How would you envision that process working? After the market structure has evolved to support widespread facilities-based competition, auctions might be employed to lower the cost of the obligation to serve. With multiple competitors available, it would be possible to run an auction in which companies bid down the necessary subsidy. In order to ensure that this public interest would be protected, a maximum subsidy would be established. 2. Could a similar process be employed to ensure service in tariffed areas where the present incumbent does not wish to have an obligation to serve? Auctions to abandon service would be even more tricky. In addition to having multiple facilities-based providers available and establishing a maximum price, rules would have to be written to preclude the incumbent from bidding. How areas would be designated for abandonment would also be an important element of the process. F:\CASES\UT\UT970325\WASHOB5 FROM DISKETTE.DOC