These following comments are submitted on behalf of the American Association of Retired Persons and the Public Counsel Section of the Washington Attorney General, pursuant to the Commission’s Notices of May 4 and 14, 1998. The comments were prepared by Dr. Mark Cooper. Dr. Cooper has presented testimony on universal service and lifeline issues in Connecticut, Florida, Hawaii, Illinois, Manitoba, Mississippi, New York, North Carolina, Ohio, Oklahoma, South Carolina and Texas as well as before the FCC and CRTC. In addition, he has conducted several major studies of universal services including Universal Service: An Historical Perspective and Policies for the 21st Century (The Benton Foundation and the Consumer Federation of America, 1996), Protecting the Public Interest in the Transition to Competition in Network Industries in The Electric Utility Industry in Transition (Public Utilities Reports and the New York State Energy Research Development Authority, 1994), Consumers with Disabilities in the Information Age: Public Policy for a Dynamic Market (The Dole Foundation, 1993), Utility Lifeline Programs: Prevalence and Performance (American Association of Retired Persons and the Consumer Federation of America, 1991), Expanding the Information Age for the 1990s: A Pragmatic Consumer Analysis (American Association of Retired Persons and the Consumer Federation of America, 1990), The Telecommunications Needs of Older, Low Income and General Consumers in the Post-Divestiture Era, (American Association of Retired Persons and the Consumer Federation of America, 1987), Low Income Households in the Post-Divestiture Era: A Study of Telephone Subscribership and Use in Michigan (Michigan Divestiture Research Fund, 1986), and Energy and Equity: Rising Energy Prices and the Living Standards of Lower Income Americans (Westview, 1982). A statement of Dr. Cooper’s qualifications is attached as Appendix A. GOAL OF UNIVERSAL SERVICE 1. What should be the goal of a Washington universal service support system and fund (USF)? In your answer, please include a separate paragraph that specifically details the ramifications your answer would have for various consumer groups, including residential and small and large business consumers. Many of the issues which are raised in the questions posed by the notice derive from the new legal structure established by the Telecommunications Act of 1996 (hereafter TA96 or the Act). .Telecommunications Act of 1996, 47 U.S.C. § 254. Therefore, it is useful to base our response on the principles of universal service laid down in that Act. Moreover, it is important to identify the full structure of principles that govern rates under the Act. The Communications Act of 1934 had one sentence dealing with universal service. 47 U.S.C. § 151, in pertinent part, states that the Communications Act of 1934 was enacted: For the purpose of regulating interstate and foreign commerce in communication by wire and radio so as to make available, so far as possible, to all people of the United States, a rapid, efficient, Nation-wide and world-wide wire and radio communication service with adequate facilities at reasonable charges…. (emphasis added) Section 254 of the TA 96 has fifteen paragraphs on the subject. The most critical language is found in two key provisions of the section. The first is Section 254(b)(1) of the Act which opens with the principle that “[q]uality services should be available at just, reasonable, and affordable rates.” The second is Section 254 (i), which restates this principle and extends the obligation to the states: Consumer Protection – The Commission and the States should ensure that universal service is available at rates that are just, reasonable and affordable.” Congress had never before used the term ”affordable” in connection with universal service, nor had it identified specific groups or areas for specific support in ensuring universal service, as it has now done in Section 254 (b)(3), which provides: Access in rural and high cost areas – Consumers in all regions of the Nation, including low-income consumers and those in rural, insular, and high cost areas, should have access to telecommunications and information services, including interexchange services and advanced telecommunication and information services, that are reasonably comparable to those services provided in urban areas and that are available at rates that are reasonably comparable to rates charged for similar services in urban areas. Congress was also more specific than it had been in the past about how rates were to be kept just, reasonable and affordable for the purposes of achieving universal service. In addition to the general requirements of Section 254 (b) (1) and 254 (i), the law also requires in Section 254 (k) that rates for service deemed to be part of universal service bear only a reasonable share of joint and common costs. Subsidy of Competitive Service Prohibited – A telecommunications carrier may not use services that are not competitive to subsidize services that are subject to competition. The Commission, with respect to interstate services, and the States, with respect to intrastate services, shall establish any necessary cost allocation rules, accounting safeguards, and guidelines to ensure that services included in the definition of universal service bear no more than a reasonable share of the joint and common costs of facilities used to provide those services. Taken together, these provisions require that a broad definition of universal service policy must be adopted. The definition of universal service has three components -- (1) access to and (2) use of telecommunications services at (3) affordable rates. Access has traditionally been defined as the dial tone -- having the telephone in the home. Use of the phone is defined as the actual placing of calls and activation of other functionalities embedded in the network. Affordability of the phone is frequently measured by estimating the percentage of income that households spend on telephones and the percentage of households with telephone service. As a succinct definition (see the response to question 14a for an elaboration of this definition), we offer the following: Universal service is the ability of all subscribers to have and use telecommunications services at rates, terms and conditions that do not cause them serious consequence or detriment and do not yield profits for service providers that are excessive. Of utmost important is the fact that the law goes farther than merely requiring affordability of service. Charges for telecommunications services cannot be increased simply because they would remain affordable; they must also be just and reasonable. Thus, the Congress clearly rejected the notion of pricing telephone service up to whatever the market will bear. Consistent with the first universal service principle, there are two pillars on which universal service stands under the law. 1Universal service in high cost areas and for low income households is to be ensured through targeted subsidies. 1Universal service for other subscribers is to be assured by the requirement that rates be just and reasonable. Given the clear public policy on how the costs of the network should be shared and the universal service goal, another principle should guide the Commission in this proceeding. 1The keys to accomplishing the dual goals of just and reasonable rates and affordable service is to ensure that all services share the costs of facilities that they use and all revenues are taken into account in determining the level of subsidies necessary to achieve universal service. Several years before the passage of TA96, AARP recommended precisely this balancing of the aspects of universal service as follows (American Association of Retired Persons and the Consumer Federation of America, Universal Service Requirements for the Information Age, 1994, pp. 2-3). EXPAND AFFORDABLE AND UNIVERSAL BASIC SERVICE Policy makers should make a commitment to lower the price of basic communications service in order to reaffirm the commitment to universal service found in the 1934 Communications Act. The following principles must be adhered to if basic service is to remain affordable for everyone in the information age: a. As revenues from video, data, and other non-basic services expand, they should be made available to lower the price of basic service, since these new services piggy-back on the existing infrastructure; b. Basic customers should be protected from bearing inappropriate risk associated with entry into new, competitive businesses. Protections should include separate subsidiaries, separate capital structures, and payments for the value of intangible assets flowing from monopoly customers; c. Users of service which require expensive upgrades and investments should bear the primary burden of these upgrades. The implications of this view of universal service for all consumers regardless of size or customer class, will be to make basic service ever more affordable. As the uses of the telecommunications network expand, the joint and common costs of the network, which are substantial, will be spread across an expanding array of services. Prices for basic service should decline. 1Should the USF program guarantee sufficient operating revenue to companies serving high-cost locations no matter how much market share is lost to competitors?* Universal service payments should be analyzed with respect to customers and the cost of serving the customer, not on the basis of a company’s profits or losses. Proposals for a revenue replacement universal service fund are unacceptable. Instead of targeting support to specific areas identified as high cost or individuals that are identified as low income, such approaches seek to have the Commission assume that if revenues decline, all such losses are due to universal service obligations. This approach makes it impossible to distinguish between universal service obligations and competitive losses. Moreover, it is anti-competitive and results in a vastly inflated universal service fund. This strategy shifts cost recovery from the rates for competitive services to the universal service fund. It forces consumers and competitors to, in effect, insure the cover incumbent local exchange company (ILEC) against competitive losses. By rejecting this “revenue replacement” view of universal service, basic service is likely to become ever more affordable as competition grows in the industry. As long as incumbents are not shielded from competitive market forces by excessive universal service funds or uneconomic rebalancing of rates, prices for basic service should decline. 3. What relationship, if any, should payments from a universal service fund bear to changes in efficiency and productivity of the recipient? Payments from the universal service fund must be adjusted to reflect gains in efficiency and productivity. Failure to do so would result in rates that are not just and reasonable. SUPPORTED SERVICES 4. Should USF provide support for each customer’s primary line only? Or should USF provide support for all lines or some number of lines greater than one but less than all lines? * The Commission cannot, as a matter of law, nor should it as a matter of public policy, restrict high cost support to primary lines only. TA 96 seeks to ensure that reasonably comparable services are available at reasonably comparable rates and to promote use of the telecommunications network for advanced services (section 254(b)(3)). To discriminate against residential and small business customers in rural areas by requiring them to pay a much higher price for second lines than their urban brethren is directly contrary to the goal of “reasonably comparable” services at “reasonably comparable” rates. To the extent that second lines have become associated with use of information services, rural households would be severely discriminated against in access to advanced services. Even if the statute could be interpreted to suggest that the universal service language in TA96 covers only primary lines, attempting to determine which line is a primary line and which is a secondary line presents an administrative nightmare. Multi-family households would be required to share lines. Large families would be at a disadvantage compared to small. Married couples would pay more than unmarried partners would. Recent testimony by GTE in Hawaii makes a number of similar points. Rebuttal Testimony and Exhibits of Dennis Weller, Chief Economist, GTE Hawaiian Telephone Co. Inc. Subject: Universal Service Fund, In the Matter of Public Utilities Commission Instituting a Proceeding on Communications, Including an Investigation of the Communications Infrastructure of the State of Hawaii, Docket No. 7702. When asked why should second lines be supported, the GTE witness observed: There are several reasons. First, it maintains a reasonable price relationship between first and second lines. Our customers generally expect that if you buy a second line from us, they will pay no more for the second line then they did for the first. This is a reasonable expectation; in most markets, the per unit price declines if you buy more of something. It also correctly reflects the relative cost of providing first and second line. It will be very difficult for us to explain to our customers why, if the first line costs nineteen dollars and 80 cents, the second line should cost 40 dollars or 100 dollars... Second, there is no good policy reason for distinguishing between primary and additional lines for universal service reasons. Underlying this policy proposal is the implicit assumption that there is a unit, a "household", that has a unique need for basic telephone service. But this is clearly not the case. Different households have different patterns of consumption, for perfectly good reasons. Consider, for example, two different households. They live on the same block, and have similar incomes. One household has a single child; the other household has ten children. If the two families go to the grocery store, we do expect them to buy the same amount of milk?.. Third, in order to limit support to second lines, we would need to define them. Since, as I have already explained, the proposal is not based on any clear concept, there is no clear basis for defining the lines to be included or excluded. In the recent California proceeding, for example, one witness suggested that one line should be supported per household; it was suggested that the company should inquire about the family relationships among the people sharing a living arrangement. Another witness proposed that one line should be provided per dwelling; he suggested that the company should consult the local plant maps in each town to make this determination. Whatever criterion is adopted, the one thing that is clear is that this idea would be difficult to administer... Fourth, when we attempt to administer a distinction between first and second lines, there will be unintended effects. Some screening procedure will be put in place, and no such procedure is ever perfect. For every wealthy family whose second line is screened out, there'll also be some other family who will be denied access to an affordable first line... Today, customers call us and we provide the services they request. We don't ask whether they deserve the services; we don't ask about their families or their living arrangements. We assume that customers can make their own decisions about where to live and about what services they need. Public Counsel and AARP recommend against a policy which would, in effect, discriminate against residential and small business customers with second lines. 5. If you propose that USF support less than all lines, should the support vary by class of customer (e.g. small and large business)? * 6a. If you propose support for one primary line, particularly for only one residential primary line, how do you propose this be administered? 6b. Could a family of three (two parents and a minor child) order three primary lines? Order two, one for each adult? 6c. How many primary lines could be ordered for a residence occupied by a group of college students? By persons who share an apartment? 6d. Could a residential customer order a primary residential line and a primary business line? * 7a. If you propose support for only one business primary line, how do you propose this be administered? 7b. Could a partnership order a primary line for each partner? 7c. Would, for example, a real estate broker who had individual agents order their own line be receiving service through many primary lines? In this example, if the lines rolled over to any other line would any or all of the lines be primary lines?* 8a. If a business or residential customer orders one line from each of three companies, would each be a primary line? 8b. If not, which of the three would be the primary line? 8c. Who would make the determination? Who would verify it? * 9. Please estimate the cost, in detail, of administering a program which supports less than all lines. The response to Question 4 renders questions 5-9 moot. 10. Should unsubscribed lines be supported? No. Unsubscribed lines should not be supported. In building cost models, an assumption about fill factors are made and levels less than 100 percent are typically used. The models assume extra capacity for normal growth and the cost of carrying that capacity is built into the calculated cost of service. Therefore, to allow companies to recover the cost of unsubscribed lines from a universal service fund would be a double recovery of cost. It is also important to recognize the difference between extra capacity that is acceptable within the framework of cost models and excess capacity, which is not. Excessive capacity should be excluded from the cost models. 11. Universal service is intended to assure affordable access to the network to use a group of enumerated services (See ESSB 6622, Sec. 1(7)(b)(i) through (ix)). Many customers desire additional features or services, for example, call waiting, voice mail, and call blocking. Should features or services in addition to those which constitute basic service, when provided to customers in high-cost locations, be priced the same, or higher or lower than they are priced in non-high-cost locations?* Vertical services should be priced the same. Generally, the costs of these services do not vary greatly on a geographic or market basis. Moreover, pricing these services the same meets the requirement that rates be reasonably comparable between rural and urban areas for reasonably comparable services. Finally, it is important to underscore that the purpose of universal service is to promote access to the network, not punish people for living in high cost areas. 12. When an incumbent local exchange carrier (ILEC) provides unbundled network elements (UNEs) to another carrier designated as an ETC, how should USF support be allocated between the companies? USF support and UNE pricing should be coordinated in two ways: 2. 1. Matching Costs And Support First, the forward-looking economic costs of a service should be equal to the sum of the unbundled network elements of that service. The whole should equal the sum of the parts in this cost analysis. Failure to achieve this equality would either allow the incumbent to overrecover costs (if UNEs exceed costs) or allow entrants to be the recipient of the implicit subsidies (if forward-looking efficient costs exceed UNEs). As long as the costs are forward-looking and efficient, they should be the basis for both UNEs and universal service calculations. With the efficient forward-looking costs identified, the principle should be that the subsidy goes with the responsibility to maintain the underlying facilities. If the unbundled element is priced at its full cost (as calculated with a forward-looking, most efficient methodology) then the purchaser of the UNE should get the subsidy. If the UNE is not priced at its full cost, then the subsidy should stay with the entity selling the UNE. If the subsidy goes to the seller of the UNE and it is priced at its full cost, there would be a double recovery. 2. Matching UNE And USF Areas The unit of analysis should be consistent between USF and UNE calculations. That is, if UNEs are offered over a specific area, e.g. urban areas, then USF should be estimated over the same area. Failure to use a consistent unit of analysis will create opportunities for overrecovery of costs and will impede competition. If the USF is calculated on an exchange-by-exchange basis, but UNE prices are calculated on a larger unit of analysis, companies can recover costs twice. By using a more disaggregated analysis for universal service than for UNE pricing, they receive prices for low cost loops that are higher than the costs of those loops. This is supposed to be offset by receiving an average price that is lower than the cost of high cost loops. If the Commission calculates USF support at a lower level of aggregation the company would also receive support for high cost loops that were already included in the average UNE price. The Commission can spend a lot of time trying to correct the problem of a mismatch between the USF area and the UNE area, backing out any overrecovery from USF funds from the price of low cost UNEs, but this is an indirect administrative contrivance that is considerably less desirable than the direct approach of matching USF and UNE areas. When the Commission defines the fundamental terms of competition by setting the UNE area, it also sets the area over which USF will be necessary. The FCC has recognized the need for consistency, in general, and the fact that USF areas should be consistent with UNE areas, in particular, in its initial universal decision. We also encourage a state, to the extent possible and consistent with the above criteria, to use its ongoing proceedings to develop permanent unbundled network element prices as a basis for its universal service cost study. This would reduce duplication and diminish arbitrage opportunities that might arise from inconsistencies between the methodologies for setting unbundled network element prices and for determining universal service support levels. In particular, we wish to avoid situations in which, because of different methodologies used for pricing unbundled network elements and determining universal service support, a carrier could receive support for the provision of universal service that differs from the rate it pays to acquire access to unbundled network elements needed to provide universal service. Consequently, to prevent differences between the pricing of unbundled network element and the determination of universal service support, we urge states to coordinate the development of cost studies for the pricing of unbundled network elements and the determination of universal service support. In the Matter of Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, CC Docket 96-45, FCC 97-157, Report and Order, May 8, 1997 (Universal Service Order), ¶ 251. 13. Should the universal service fund be used to pay for infrastructure necessary to provide service to potential customers who do not reside within established company service areas?* (Please see material related to Obligation To Serve in Docket No. UT-970325.) Please refer to the comments of Public Counsel related to “obligation to serve” in Docket No. UT 970325. The incumbent has had and continues to have the obligation to serve all. It is the carrier of last resort (COLR). The incumbent has ubiquitous facilities. It has deployed those facilities using significant resources and enjoying significant advantages provided by ratepayers, including a monopoly position and regulatory rights to an opportunity to recover costs. The pervasive market presence and longstanding name recognition conferred on the incumbent also endow it with substantial assets as competition increases in the industry. The obligation to serve is a “burden” placed on the incumbents and compensated by historical and ongoing benefits of immense value. Incumbents are directly compensated by setting rates that are, in the aggregate, just and reasonable. They are provided an opportunity to recover prudently incurred used and useful costs. Should costs increase due to an increase in the burden of its carrier of last resort obligation, they can make a showing that they are in need of a rate increase. New entrants have no such opportunity. Incumbents are also compensated for specific expenses in cases where such expenses would be large. Indirectly, the benefits of the monopoly, incumbent ubiquitous network compensate the incumbent. Given the current market structure, with virtually no change in market share and no observable price competition, the obligation to serve falls fairly on the incumbent. With that as a given, at present the fund should not be used to provide special support for provision of service where an incumbent is already obligated to provide such service and receives compensation. Only as market structure actually changes and in coordination with other changes in the approach to the obligation to serve, would such a use of these funds be justified. At some point in the future, when competition has balanced revenue opportunities and new entrants have facilities deployed that could shoulder the obligation to serve, alternative approaches may be necessary. Contributions to a universal service fund to support the obligation to extend service or sharing of the obligation to extend facilities may be necessary at that point. AFFORDABILITY AND COMPARABILITY 14a. What rate(s) for basic telecommunications service are affordable in Washington? As previously noted, the definition of universal service has three components -- access to the phone, use of the phone, and afford-ability. Universal service is the ability of all households to have and use a phone at rates that do not strain the household budget. A narrow definition of universal service as simple access to the phone should be rejected because the telephone is a necessity and people will cling to it. Even if households do not drop off the network, we must still ask whether they are able to use the phone as the basic means of communication in the last quarter of the twentieth century. For the past half-century we have woven the phone into the fabric of daily life. We have let decisions about where to live, where to locate services, how to acquire information, and how to allocate our time be fundamentally influenced by the ease of access to unlimited local calls. The telephone has become the mainstay of daily communications. While it is easy to conceive of a way of life in which the telephone does not play this vital role, it is not the way of life we live in this country. At the same time that we ask whether households are able to use the phone, we must also ask whether the cost of having and using the phone places a strain on the household budget. It does not suffice to say that if a household has a phone it must be affordable, regardless of how much of a burden it places on the household budget. Affordability is more complex than that. In this context the test of affordability is not simply whether or not people keep the phone, or whether or not they use it, but how much of a burden a normal level of consumption of this vital necessity places on the household budget. Households will continue to subscribe to the network because the phone is a necessity, but if they are forced to pay more for this necessity and reduce their consumption of other necessities, then the phone is not truly affordable. It is seriously diminishing the living standard of the household. These observations on the nature of the telephone and its use can be briefly summarized by a familiar economic measure -- the elasticity of demand. This gauges the rate at which demand changes in response to a change in price. The elasticity of demand is measured as the percentage change in demand that occurs in response to a one- percent change in price. Demand elasticities are generally negative. When prices increase, demand decreases (conversely, when prices decrease, demand increases). Telephone demand elasticities are small. A one percent increase in price will cause a reduction in demand which is less than one percent. In the case of the telephone, it is considerably less than one percentage point. It has become widely acknowledged that the elasticity of demand for access (availability) is very low. Increases in price elicit very small reductions in demand. See generally Lester Taylor, Telecommunications Demand: A Survey and Critique (1994). It turns out, however, that the elasticity of demand for use is also quite low. The demand response to usage price increases is somewhat larger than those for access but still quite small. People do not want the telephone as an alarm box. They apparently want it as a means of communications that requires being able to use it. It can be generally concluded that the long run elasticity of demand for access is in the range of -.01 to -.2 and the long run elasticity for use is about in the range of -.2 to -.4. That is, all other things being equal, a ten- percent increase in the price of access results in about a one- percent decrease in demand for access. A ten- percent increase in the price of use results in about a three- percent decrease in the demand for use. Lower income households have been found to have considerably higher elasticities of demand. The low demand response to price increases for both access and use means that one cannot analyze the third aspect of universal service -- affordability -- with reference only to the reduced access charge. One must recognize that households will struggle to keep and use the telephone at levels fairly close to the average in order to have a level of communications commensurate with a decent standard of living. Assessing affordability in this context means that the test of affordability is not simply whether or not people keep and use the phone, but how much of a burden a decent level of consumption of this vital necessity places on the household budget. For this reason, making access and use more affordable for poor households that already have service should be considered a part of the goal of universally affordable service. Dictionary definitions support this view. Webster’s gives the primary definition of “affordable” as a relative concept: -- (1) (a) To manage to bear without serious detriment; (b) To manage to pay for or incur the cost of. Webster's Third New Int